The Vital Role of Prices
The legend says that in the 1980’s a Soviet official asked
economist Paul Seabright who was in charge of London’s bread supply. The
economist answer was, ‘nobody’. That’s of course true, there’s no single person in charge
of the supply of essential goods in a market economy.
The answer to that question is, as Leonard Read’s story “I, pencil” describes, a complex and intertwined network of people
and businesses that delivers the amount of goods and services required. The
main tool they all use to find out what’s required is the pricing signal.
Prices are the most essential tool for the market economies
and in most cases, they are not designed or controlled by a central authority
or government, they are just the result of spontaneous order of dispersed
market forces.
A simple form of vast knowledge
Since economist Friedrich Hayek writings, prices have been
seen as the free and efficient nature of market economies, before then nobody
paid much attention to its nature, it was taken as a given, part of the natural
order of things.
Hayek studied the problem of knowledge and information in
markets, his central thesis being, the market price system is essential for
communicating information and coordinating transactions wherever knowledge is
dispersed, and the future uncertain.
In that sense, market prices are a spectacularly compact and
reliable source of information. A single number that condenses all the relevant
current macroeconomic information; the existing supply, the cost curve, the
average costs of transport, labour, energy and capital intensity, the average
of forecasts and expectations as of today, the existing demand, the value and
volume of stocks and inventories, and the weight each variable has for market
players. A change in any of those will inevitably change the price.
And this is the extraordinary thing about prices, such vast
amount of macroeconomic information can’t be held by a single individual or
group. A single agent can’t possess a complete knowledge of a competitive
market that would guide them on their decisions. The signalling system of
prices though, in a perfect competitive market, do provide this to each agent’s
decisions.
Hayek said,: “The marvel is that in a case like that of a
scarcity of one raw material, without an order being issued, without more than
perhaps a handful of people knowing the cause, tens of thousands of people
whose identity could not be ascertained by months of investigation, are made to
use the material or its products more sparingly, that is they move to the right
direction.”
This is the “the price system as a kind of system of
telecommunications which enables individual producers to watch merely the
movement of a few pointers”
And Hayek again: “The most significant fact about [prices]
is the economy of knowledge with which it operates, or how little the
individual participants need to know in order to be able to take the right
action. In abbreviated form, by a kind of symbol, only the most essential
information is passed on and passed on only to those really concerned”
Certain requirements
Not all is so simple of course, commodity boom and bust
cycles and financial crisis, have revealed that the price system, even in a
relatively free and liquid set of markets, can give profoundly distorted
signals.
Prices do come natural to markets, but for a market to have
an effective price signalling mechanism (or to have perfect information),
certain conditions are required; transparency, liquidity, information
symmetry... by its nature, many commodity markets do not feature these
conditions.
One notable criticism of perfect information markets was put
forth by Grossman and Stiglitz in 1981. They argued that markets cannot achieve
perfect efficiency when it comes to information. The act of searching for and
gathering information about market prices always incurs a cost, making
arbitrage expensive and preventing markets from seamlessly conveying all
available information. Consequently, enhancing and optimizing the efficiency of
information transmission becomes crucial for both market efficiency and its
participants.
Information costs
In 1997, out of the coast of southern India, in Kerala,
local fishermen were, as they always did, facing the following dilemma; every
late afternoon after a catch they had to decide at what port they would deliver
their catch. They had no information about what the supply was at their closest
port nor the other ports of the area. They didn’t know the best price they
could get for their catch. Because of fuel costs and time restrictions, they
only had one shot. In many cases, the fishermen chose the wrong port, in not
few cases it was even worse, the catch had to be dump into the sea because the
market chosen was saturated. Harvard
economist Robert Jensen studied and surveyed that market*, on average 7% of the
catches were dumped. That was highly inefficient, Jensen reported that there
were days when catches were dumped on one port and on the next port buyers went
home empty-handed.
But in 1997 a disruptive technology changed all that, mobile
phones were introduced in the region. Fishermen now called ports while still on
sea and got the up-to-date prices at all the regional ports. They could then
take an informed decision about where
to head their boats.
Jensen found that now waste disappeared and price
differences between ports dropped hugely as the “law of one price” would have
predicted.
Everyone benefited, fishermen profits went up on average by
8% and the average price at ports went down by 4% according to his study. This
efficiency effects are still enjoyed today.
This illustrates perfectly the positive importance of
information in markets, and how they improve efficiency in imperfect markets and
so everyone’s welfare.
End quote
To end this article, nothing better than a quote from
economist Douglas North, 1993 Nobel laureate in Economics:
“Economic growth throughout history could only be realized
by creating an institutional and organizational structure that would induce
productivity enhancing activity. […] A source of improving productivity that
lowered transaction costs and information costs was the printing of prices of
various commodities […]” **
* “The digital
provide: information, market performance and welfare in the South Indian
fisheries sector” by Robert Jensen, QJE, Aug 2007.
** “Institutions and productivity in history” by Douglass C.
North, Washington University, St. Louis, 1991
Comments